The Channel logo

Opinion

Tim Worstall

Contact Mail Follow Twitter RSS feed
Tim Worstall is an Englishman who has failed at many things. Thus his turn to writing, the last refuge of many who could make a living no other way. He is, as an example of his business and financial perspicacity, the head of the international scandium oligopoly: the only commodity which has not risen in price in the past decade.
By | Tim Worstall 24th October 2011 11:43

Disk drive crisis: Economists are terrible weathermen

How globalisation becomes a washout

Hang on a minute. This globalisation thing, isn't it supposed to have stopped nonsense like this? You know, it rains a bit and so we all run out of something?

When we all lived on what could be grown or made within 5 miles a bit of flooding understandably led to shortages, but now we've the whole world to supply us why does Thailand having floods mean hard drives are in short supply? Isn't this one of the things that the brave new era of globalisation was meant to stop?

Well, yes, it was actually, but we've got three different bits of economics interacting here and how they interact depends upon what specific product, in what sort of industry with what industry characteristics we're talking about.

The first one, the one about globalisation allowing diversity of supply, yup, that's usually true. It certainly is for things like food, which we can indeed get from many parts of the world. Those Thai floods are going to crock the rice harvest there, that's for sure, and 200 years ago that would have meant at the very least some hungry times if not mass starvation. That we, or the Thais more importantly, can get rice from India, Burma, the US, quite possibly Brazil for all I know, means that it's a pain, not a death sentence. So score one for globalisation there.

However, there's another part of economics entirely that looks at the effects of clustering.

Where economic geography doesn't entirely depend upon actual geography (the way say mining or farming depends on the actual piece of land), we can find that as we liberalise trade then some certain specific part of it congregates in one very specific geographical area. We've known about this inside countries for a long time. Cotton was largely Manchester, tin bashing Birmingham, shipbuilding Tyneside.

Even today if you want to set up a UK pottery you do it in Stoke on Trent (one this past year in fact), play with non-ferrous metals in Sheffield or Rotherham (a new Ti factory a couple of years back), chlorine chemistry is Tyneside again, fluorine chemistry Manchester.

These are simply the places with the trained workforce, the accountants and lawyers who understand the industry, the suppliers all there and ready so if you were to want to start up that's where you'd go and do so. And of course each and every company that does so adds a little more to the economic pull of the place as with each incoming asteroid adding that bit more to the gravity of a planet.

What perhaps some hadn't realised is that when the international trade barriers came down the same might be true internationally. That we'd end up with certain industries congregating in certain parts of the world for no other real reason than lots of that sort of industry were already there. There's no particular reason, other than it actually happened, why there's a little region of northern Italy that makes the majority of the world's spectacle frames, or for one town in China making 80 per cent of the world's socks.

Which is one of the things that seems to have happened with the hard drive industry. Here there is a reason, beyond mere happenstance, for it to have happened though.

The Thais thought about this quite a bit. They've got low wages, making hard drives is labour intensive (not the making of the parts, but the piecing them together) and, well, what the heck, Singapore has managed quite nicely out of this industry, so why not give it a go? So, tax breaks galore and once threy've got the industry in then it grows like Topsy. Thailand is not just assembling some large percentage of the world's hard drives, the component manufacturers have gone there too to supply the factories.

What could possibly go wrong...

Excellent, so we've got the ability to have a much wider supplier base as a result of globalisation and also the possibility of that supplier base clustering and actually making it more, not less, vulnerable to geographically specific shocks. How they play out against each other just sort of depends, which is what the answer is so often in economics, “it depends”.

The third thing we've got is economies of scale.

Now all you technical types are entirely familiar with this, although you tend to call it network effects. Windows sells trillions because everyone uses Windows. Facebook has youth by the the short and curlies because all youths are on Facebook. Paul Krugman got his Nobel largely for work in this very field: when might globalisation, the freeing of trade, lead not to more suppliers but to fewer? When might the economies of scale (the network effects if you like) just keep going so that we end up with not hundreds of producers, but only one, or perhaps just a handful?

Economists have always been aware of economies of scale, of course, as are most people. But economists, unlike most people, are also aware of diseconomies of scale. Sure, making a million of something might be cheaper per unit than making 100: but what about the costs of managing an organisation capable of making one million things? The accretion of layers of bureaucracy perhaps, or the slow down in technical innovation from being part of a multi-layered organisation (vide just about every tech company - even the likes of Google and Oracle - that buys in bright ideas that would never survive its own development bureaucracy). What Krugman mused upon was what happens if the economies of scale are so great as to continue to overwhelm these diseconomies even as a company moves to globally bestriding colossus?

OK, put like that it doesn't sound all that amazing, not Nobel level stuff, but you get the gongs for (a) being first to muse along these lines and (b) being able to prove what would happen. Which is what he did do and he was quite right too.

We can put this is Adam Smith terms too: the division and specialisation of labour (the dreaded pin factory for anyone who ever did any economics). If we split up production into multiple stages then each worker is going to get better at their specific task (both Smith and Marx warned they'd get bored stupid too but that's another argument) at hand. So, now we've got a team of specialists, each doing their part of the divided labour, we can get more production from our division and specialisation. What we've learned more recently is that this also applies to things that aren't just direct labour. Teams of hard drive designers seem to be better at designing hard drives than people who flit from graphics cards to hard drives to motherboards.

No, this isn't absolutely true, for there are still huge benefits to cross-fertilisation across disciplines, but it is more true than we had perhaps thought at one time. Which is where we get these ever increasing returns to scale from in some industries, where this is indeed true.

I dimly recall the time of the Kyoto earthquake in 1995 (forgive the dimly, I was more worried about being paid for a delivery made two days before the quake; we got the cash, just, a transfer on the last working day before it hit) and how the computer world was in uproar. Yes, death and destruction, appalling, but we found out that the only company in the world that made the glue (this is the dimly part, I think it was glue) to stick chips into their casings was at the bottom of the rubble.

Which is sort of but not quite where we are with the deadly Thai floods and the looming hard drive shortage.

Globalisation has made it possible to allocate work across the resources of the planet. We get our hard drives assembled by the Thai women making €200 a month in factories (as opposed to a possibly less pleasant career earning higher wages in the bars) but there's also these other effects as well. Economies of scale seem to be still large, which is why the number of drive manufacturers has gone, according to one estimate, from 20 to only 7 in the past few years. We've also got these clustering effects, where although those manufacturers might have multiple manufacturing locations, they tend to end up putting their factories close to those of their competitors.

How it all works out in any specific industry depends upon the specifics of that very industry: and that working out might well mean that globalisation does not lead to a larger number of suppliers nor even to greater reliability of supply. It, as so often, just depends. ®

comment icon Read 27 comments on this article alert Send corrections

Opinion

Chris Mellor

Drives nails forged with Red Hat iron into VCE's coffin
Sleep Cycle iOS app screenshot

Trevor Pott

Forget big-spending globo biz: it's about the consumer... and he's desperate for a nap
Steve Bennet, ex-Symantec CEO

Chris Mellor

Enormo security firm needs to get serious about acquisitions

Features

Windows 8.1 Update  Storeapps Taskbar
Chinese Buffet self-service
Chopping down the phone tree to scrump low-hanging fruit
An original member of the System/360 family announced in 1964, the Model 50 was the most powerful unit in the medium price range.
Big Blue's big $5bn bet adjusted, modified, reduced, back for more
Microsoft CEO Satya Nadella
Redmond needs to discover the mathematics of trust